PADU And The Myth Of Data Driven Policy Decisions

The Malaysian Government recently launched the Central Database Hub (PADU), an effort led by the Economics Ministry to bring together information held by various ministries and government agencies into one, allowing the government a clearer picture of its 33.5 million population. Launched with great enthusiasm, PADU aims to allow the government to dive deeper beyond its citizen’s gross income in determining where help and subsidies should be directed.

Immediately after the official announcement, PADU project was welcomed with two criticisms which represent the core of any criticism linked to the most recent information technology innovations: cyber security and data protection. While a security breach has been immediately identified, rising concerns are emerging with the utilization of data themselves.

“While these two issues are of primary concern, with regard in particular to the protection of individuals’ privacy, they still miss the central point, the original sin of a project such as PADU”, Dr Carmelo Ferlito, CEO of the Center for Market Education (CME), commented. “The real issue – Dr Ferlito explained – lies in believing that data per se can inform policy making”.

CME suggests that, while data are important for informed decision making, they do not represent the totality of what is necessary when making policy decisions. Dr Ferlito says take the example of targeted subsidies, which seem to be, in this particular moment, the core target for the PADU implementation. Policy makers will decide that targeted subsidies are destined to those households earning below a certain threshold and PADU can indeed be the right tool to have a better identification (always temporary and ex-post) of who the potential beneficiaries are. However, what data cannot tell is which is the right threshold: a qualitative decision is – and will always be – necessary, and it cannot be dictated by data. Rather, it depends on the vision of policy makers, who are not super humans with super knowledge, but fallible human beings, equipped with beliefs and biases.

An additional example: economists trained in certain traditions believe that an increase in the rate of saving is good for the economy and will bring about higher and better growth; policy making should thus incentivize it. Other economists, instead, argue that a higher rate of saving will reduce growth and employment. Very little is objective in economics: facts and data are always, and inevitably, read with interpretative lenses.

CME stresses that there is no amount of data which will allow for objective and value-free policy decisions: data-driven policy decisions remain very much affected by subjective value judgements (dictated by political targets).

“This is not good or bad, but a matter of fact, which must bring us to two main conclusions: policy is an art more than a science and, as such, it requires a great dose of humility”, Dr Ferlito explained.

This is just the natural consequence of the realisation that the economy is a complex, living and emergent organism. The starting point to deal with it should be the astonished realization that, without central planning and interferences, but with the right institutional framework, economic coordination does happen at a great extent. Policy decisions, often based on a pretence of absolute (and data-driven) knowledge, happen to be, in many cases, the reason behind the lack of coordination (in many cases, then, what we label market failures are indeed policy failures).

The art of addressing eventual economic imperfections, thus, should be based on the observation of the conditions that make the economy naturally work, rather than the forced application of policy makers’ visions, targets and dreams. 

Previous articleChina’s Import To Narrow As Real Estate Downturn Weighs: Maybank
Next articleSingapore To Hand Out Cash Aid To 2 Million Citizens In February

LEAVE A REPLY

Please enter your comment!
Please enter your name here